DMCA
Licensing Agreements (2007)
Citations
677 |
Essays in the theory of risk-bearing,
- Arrow
- 1971
(Show Context)
Citation Context ...it will simultaneously satisfy a potential buyer’s need and further impede any subsequent market transaction. For decades, economists have analyzed this underlying problem of the information paradox (=-=Arrow, 1971-=-; Winter, 2006). 1 An earlier version of this paper has been presented at the 66th Annual Meeting of the Academy of Management 2006 in Atlanta, Georgia. The authors thank two anonymous reviewers for t... |
106 |
Licensing the market for technology,
- Arora, &Arora
- 2003
(Show Context)
Citation Context ...erformance-oriented contracts used to exploit the value embedded in technical knowledge (Teece, 1986). Licensing activities have motivated a large body of literature covering topics like reasons for (=-=Arora and Fosfuri, 2003-=-; Mottner and Johnson, 2000; Saracho, 2002) and results of (Arrow, 1962; Rockett, 1990) granting licenses, profit maximizing licensing strategies (Fosfuri, 2006; Kamien and Tauman, 2002; Katz and Shap... |
68 |
Licensing in the Theory of Innovation.”
- Gallini, Winter
- 1985
(Show Context)
Citation Context ...6; Poddar and Sinha, 2004), ways to distribute the value created between licensor and licensee (Kamien and Tauman, 1986), timing of licensing (before or after developing a technology) (Gallini, 1984; =-=Gallini and Winter, 1985-=-; Shapiro, 1985) and the types of innovations that are transferred (Arora, 1995; Katz and Shapiro, 1985). One stream of research analyzes in detail the information given by licensing agreements. Major... |
68 |
Is knowledge power? Knowledge flows, subsidiary power and rent-seeking within MNCs’.
- Mudambi, Navarra
- 2004
(Show Context)
Citation Context ...ss knowledge into a specific, standardized expression which can be understood by everyone who is acquainted with this way of expression (Boisot and Child, 1988) 6intellectual property rights (IPRs) (=-=Mudambi and Navarra, 2004-=-; Nonaka and Takeuchi, 1995; Teece, 1998). Explicit knowledge is a public good (Arrow, 1962; Dyer and Nobeoka, 2000; Grant, 2002; Kogut and Zander, 1993; Machlup, 1980; Martin and Salomon, 2003). Once... |
34 |
Cross Licensing of Complementary Technologies,”
- Kamien
- 1992
(Show Context)
Citation Context ...ry technology and allows an earlier introduction of a product based on each partners’ technology. But at the same time this also provokes the creation of substitutes for the products of each partner (=-=Fershtman and Kamien, 1992-=-). Moreover, cross-licensing might foster collusive behavior of both parties since it either increases (in the case of imperfect substitutes) the probability of a market entry (Eswaran, 1993) and/or e... |
33 | The role of information in licensing contract design - Macho-Stadler, Martinez-Giralt, et al. - 1996 |
23 |
A knowledge-based view of cooperative interorganizational relationships
- Choi, Lee
- 1997
(Show Context)
Citation Context ...involuntarily (Nelson et al., 1982). They allow one to be aware of one’s tacit knowledge but at the same time to be unable to articulate it. 4 Synonyms for this dichotomy are codified and uncodified (=-=Choi and Lee, 1997-=-; Teece, 1998), objective and subjective, prepositional and personal, declarative and procedural (Grant, 1996; Kakabadse, et al., 2001; Nahapiet and Ghoshal, 1998; Winter, 1987), internal and external... |
17 |
The global acquisition, leverage, and protection of technological competences,
- McEvily, Eisenhardt, et al.
- 2004
(Show Context)
Citation Context ... not only consider technology primarily as a source of future revenue but as a currency or a bargaining chip to be used during the negotiation process in order to achieve their individual objectives (=-=McEvily, et al., 2004-=-; Nickerson, 1996). In view of these considerations, we interpret the existence of contractual terms referring to cross-licenses as an equal mean to compensate the licensor and, therefore, assume: Hyp... |
13 | From Words to Numbers: How to Transform Qualitative Data into Meaningful Quantitative Results - Auer-Srnka, Koeszegi - 2007 |
6 |
The property right paradigm. The journal of economic history
- Alchian, Demsetz
- 1973
(Show Context)
Citation Context ...eses 2.5.1. Hypotheses: Negotiation period The overall aim of a licensing agreement is to determine the rights and duties of both parties. In general, we can identify four classes of property rights (=-=Alchian and Demsetz, 1973-=-; Coase, 1960; Demsetz, 1967) that can be licensed. A licensee can obtain the right (1) to use, (2) consume and (3) obtain income from and (4) to alienate attributes of the subject of contract. Attrib... |
6 |
Compensation in international licensing agreements
- Aulakh, Cavusgil, et al.
- 1998
(Show Context)
Citation Context ...er in case that one party infringes a substantial condition of the agreement. 2.4.2. Contract period: Compensation provisions Empirical results show a considerable variety of compensation provisions (=-=Aulakh, et al., 1998-=-; Bessy and Brousseau, 1998; Merwin and Warner, 1996). Apart from lump 13sum payments, the most common means to determine license fees are recurring amount payments and royalty rates. Royalty rates c... |
6 |
Information Assets, Technology and Organization," Management Science (40:12
- Brynjolfsson
- 1994
(Show Context)
Citation Context ...ositional and personal, declarative and procedural (Grant, 1996; Kakabadse, et al., 2001; Nahapiet and Ghoshal, 1998; Winter, 1987), internal and external (Zack, 1999) or alienable and non-alienable (=-=Brynjolfsson, 1994-=-; Foss, 2002) knowledge. 5 In this context, codification refers to the possibility to compress knowledge into a specific, standardized expression which can be understood by everyone who is acquainted ... |